Sunday, May 26, 2019
Implications of the Bertrand Model
In 1893 French economist Joseph Bertrand developed his Bertrand model of competition from his review of Antoine Cournots study of a Spring Water duopoly. His chiding lay with how trues in oligopolies compete. In his model rigids compete with bells rather than Cornots quantities. (REFERENCE TO SPANISH JOURNAL) The model consists of two riotouss who descend prices simultaneously and independently (HUGH GRAVIELLE AND AY REES, MICROECONOMICES), jean tiral explains this as when mavin firm sets its price it is ignorant to its rivals price, rather it anticipates what they will charge.It is assumed products are homogeneous and perfective substitutes (ECCSTRAT) and due to the nature of the product the firm supplying output at the junior-gradeest price will gain the entire market demand. (GB ) This firm will have to supply all the outgoing demand at the price they have set gb1 from this an important self-assertion of the model is that there are no capacity constraints, that both fi rms have the like marginal cost, which remains constant, and that demand is liner.GB2 As stated, the entire market demand for homogeneous products will go to the firm offering the lowest price, although if both firms were to cheat on at the same price a sharing rule must be assumed GB2. Using an example from the ((((((( lets suppose the market demand for a homogeneous product is given by, Q = 120-p (where Q is quantity demanded and p is price charged). The marginal cost (MC) for both producers is, C=$30, and both producers sell output at p=c=$30. The demand for each producer is Q=0. 5*120-p=45.Lets say producer A increased their price to c=$31, the entire market demand would agitate to producer B who would now have a demand function of Qb=120-c=90, while producer A would have zero demand. However if producer A had reduced their price to c=$29, they would capture the entire market demand through charging the lowest cost, however they would make a $1 loss in each product sold. Fro m this, the Nash equilibrium for the Bertrand model lies where P=MC, with demand so heavily influenced by price producers do not want to be slice by rivals.With P=MC no rival will undercut as zero profits are preferable to negative profits, and any firm trying to charge above the MC and make ordained profits will receive no sales. The suggestion is the addition of one firm restores perfect market competition (Jean Tirole, 1998), moving the market form monopoly power and profits (maximum inefficiency) to perfectly competitive (maximum efficiency). It had been deemed a paradox as it is difficult to believe that two firms in a duopolistic market can make zero profits.We are able to resolve Bertrands paradox through relaxing and of the three built-in assumptions of the model (intro to industrial org l. M. B Cabrail). In order to analyse its practical relevance and its implications, this essay will now give examples of where the paradox can be deconstructed. The first example of a sol ution comes from a combination of two assumptions, the first is the absence of capacity constraints, and the second firms make decisions independently.In the model whichever firm firm is charging the lowest price will receive the entire market demand, and is expected to supply all forthcoming demand at the price it has set (old xavior). at that place are few situations in the real world where one firm could satisfy the demand of the whole market. Using the previous example, producer B gained the entire market demand (Q=120-$30=90). Lets assume producer B has a capacity constraint below 90 units.There is now a proportion of the market that can only be satisfied by producer A, who can use monopoly power and make positive profits as the only producer. (managerial Economics a strategic approach). This example shows how with the inclusion of a common real world problem, Bertrands proposed equilibrium of price equal to marginal cost is deconstructed. A second implication of capacity cons traints is their effect on collision between firms. Collusion reduces market competiveness, firms tactically hold to set prices above particular levels and to not to engage in price wars,(REF).A positive relationship between excess capacity and collusion was set by David and Deneckere, who found excess capacity is a prerequisite for stable collusion while it provides a stronger bargaining position within cartels (QUOTE TO JOURNALS THAT ARE ON JUIBILEE AND WOLF). These effects have been see in oil cartel OPEC, which has existed since the second world war and where the largest producer, Saudi Arabia can flood the market if small producers cheat on their quotas. (paul Pijush).Through years of controlling supply and therefore price the carte will receive one trillion dollars in revenues this year, (Wall street post). The prisoners predicament is a particular plunk for between two captured prisoners that illustrates why cooperation is difficult to maintain even when mutually benefici al (REF). It helps to demonstrate the logic behind Bertrands Paradox. Both firms would benefit from charging a price higher(prenominal) than marginal cost, however at this level both firms have an incentive to undercut one another. (managerial economics).If the rules of the game can be changed each agent would receive a higher revenue payoff. (Global Business Mike W peng). Two companies who saw this were General electric car (GE) and Westinghouse. In the early 1960s these two companies controlled over 98% of the US market for large turbine generators. Prior to purchase, electric utilities would negotiate with GE and Westinghouse who, as in Bertrand competition, competed on price. Government owned utilities accounted for twenty five percent of the market share and by law had to purchase from the cheapest provider and publish the price.The two firms generated low profit, as Bertrand competition predicts, until GE changed the rules of the game by introducing a price book. The process effectively set a higher market price and guaranteed higher profits, the price publishing behaviour continued successfully until 1975 when the US Department of Justice investigated the industry. Price books were ruled to breach anti-competition laws and the firms were fined. The book, Technology and Transformation in the American Electric Utility Industry by Richard F.Hirsh goes into this example in much greater depth. This is an important example as it demonstrates that Bertrand competition can exist in the real world. However the assumption of zero profits, or in the example, low profits encourages companies to collude to set higher prices and make positive profits. The Bertrand model overly assumes that with the entrant of a second firm into the market, and the subsequent Nash equilibrium, price equal to marginal cost, removes the need for policy makers to intervene.However form the previous example this is manifestly false as policy makers did have to intervene and sanctions w ere made. To stress this point, another example Pakistans Federal Cabinet moved powers of oil price fixation to the Oil Companies Advisory Committee in 2001, through flawed polices profits of the duopolists Pakistan State Oil and Shell Pakistan increased by 232% between 2001 to 2005. which lead to advertise state involvement to enforce price restrictions and encourage competition. (competition reporter. 25,05,2009).In the Bertrand model we assumed that both firms had the same costs of production which remain constant. It is an extreme assumption that two firms would incur exactly the same costs when producing their products, let us now assume that one firm had a cost advantage, i. e. firm A can produce marginally less expensively that firm B (cA
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.